end include: _nav
bobbarnetson
author_tags looks like: bob barnetson

Five ways Alberta can improve its regressive labour laws

Alberta’s regressive labour laws have played an important role in making Alberta the least unionized province in Canada. While Alberta’s recently elected New Democratic Party government is likely to address a number of long-standing issues in Alberta labour laws – such as unconstitutional prohibitions on strikes, incorporating the Rand formula, shortening the period between certification applications and votes, and removing provisions limiting organizing in the construction industry – none of these changes are likely to address the alarming and ongoing decline in union density in the province.

Across Canada, union density – the percentage of workers who are union members – has been in been in long-term decline, dropping from 38% in 1981 to 30% in 2012. A majority (56.9%) of unionized workers work in the public sector and the unionization rate is higher in the public sector (71.4%) than in the private-sector (16.4%).

unionizationrates.jpg

Union density in Alberta broadly mirrored these national patterns. In 2014, 22.1% of Alberta workers were unionized. The majority (60.8%) of unionized workers work in Alberta’s public sector and the unionization rate is higher in the public sector (68.8%) than in the private sector (10.8%).

Private-sector unionization is concentrated in the construction, manufacturing, trade, and transportation and warehousing industries. Of particular concern is that Alberta’s labour laws make it difficult for workers in the service sector (where women comprise approximately 60% of the workforce) to exercise their associational rights.

Alberta’s regressive labour laws – which reflect overt hostility towards organized labour by the Social Credit (1935–1971) and Progressive Conservative (1971–2015) governments – have contributed to Alberta’s low union density. For example, research demonstrates that requiring a vote to certify a new bargaining unit results in fewer organizing drives and a lower success rate.

Union density matters because countries with high union density tend to see relatively small wage differences and few instances of precarious work. This outcome tends to advantage women and racialized workers, who otherwise disproportionately hold low-wage and precarious jobs.

Interestingly, approximately 33% of Canadian workers who are not in a union say they would like to be and, overall, 52% of all Canadian workers would like to be or remain in a union.

One purpose of labour law is to ensure workers can exercise their associational rights. Alberta’s labour laws constrain Albertans’ ability to do so, and require change. There is a range of policy options available to the government that, individually or in concert, would enhance Albertans’ abilities in this regard.

Five possible reforms are outlined below: card-check certification, first-contract arbitration, remedial certification in cases of significant employer interference in union organizing, sectoral bargaining, and minority unionism. The first three changes are less controversial, and entail strengthening workers’ abilities to unionize under the current system of labour relations. More controversial are the notions of extending sectoral bargaining outside of Alberta’s construction industry, or allowing workers access to some form of minority unionism to remedy the issue of up to one-third of non-unionized workers being denied the opportunity to meaningful exercise their associational rights.

1. Card-Check Certification

Canada’s current labour regime is based upon the US Wagner model. Under Wagnerism, a government-appointed Labour Relations Board is responsible for certifying a union as the official bargaining agent for a group of workers.

Legislation based on the Wagner model has provided workers in standard employment relationships (i.e., full-time, full-year employment with a single employer) and at large industrial worksites with reasonably good access to union representation. This approach has worked less well in the service sector (e.g., banking, retail, food service) or for workers who are employed precariously.

There are two basic approaches to unionization under the Wagner model: mandatory certification votes and card-check. Most jurisdictions require a mandatory certification vote. In this model, the union demonstrates to the Labour Relations Board evidence that a certain percentage of workers (40% in Alberta) wish to join a union. The Board then holds a certification vote and certifies the union as the official bargaining agent if a majority of workers who vote are in favour of certification.

Under the card-check model, if the union shows the Labour Relations Board evidence that a certain percentage of workers are union members, the Board then automatically certifies the union. Up until 1977, all Canadian jurisdictions used card-check certification. Presently, only Quebec, Prince Edward Island, Manitoba, and Ontario’s construction sector do so, with the percentage required for automatic certification varying between 50% plus one and 65% of the workers in the proposed bargaining unit. Unions which cannot demonstrate support that meets the card-check threshold can still achieve certification through a certification vote.

The evidence in Canada is clear: card-check certification provisions result in more certification drives by unions and more successful certification applications. The most robust analysis is of BC’s move from card-check to mandatory votes in 1984, which saw a 50% reduction in certification drives and a 19% reduction is successful private-sector drives. A return to card check certification in 1993 saw the number of organizing drives increase, as well as a 19% increase is successful private-sector unionization drives.

The absence of any effect of these changes on public sector unionization (where employers are less likely to oppose unionization) suggests that requiring mandatory votes enabled employers who opposed unionization to thwart drives by giving the employer notice of the drive and time to act against it. Other studies have found similar card-check effects.

In short, returning Alberta to card-check certification will increase both the amount of organizing and the success rate of organizing drives.

2. Remedial Certification

In addition to card-check certification, the government of Alberta could enhance workers’ willingness and ability to join unions by modifying existing provisions in the Labour Relations Code to allow the Labour Relations Board to grant automatic certification in cases of significant employer interference in organizing campaigns.

Remedial certification is necessary because up to 80% of employers overtly and actively resist union certification efforts. This employer interference profoundly impacts workers’ ability to exercise their associational rights free from undue employer influence.

For example, employers engaging in unfair labour practices – a subset of all forms of employer resistance to unionization – were found to reduce the chance of certification by 14%, to increase the likelihood of encountering serious bargaining difficulties by up to 35%, and to increase the likelihood of early decertification by up to 57%.

The public policy purpose of remedial certification is to eliminate the incentive for the employer to meddle in union organizing drives. The evidence from Ontario is that existence of the remedial certification provisions is often enough to dissuade employers from committing unfair labour practices.

While Alberta’s Labour Relations Code currently allows the Labour Relations Board to remedially certify a union, it can only do so if that certification is confirmed by a vote of the affected employees. Since the purpose of employer interference is generally to pressure workers into voting against the union, conditioning remedy on a (likely poisoned) vote seems nonsensical.

3. First-Contract Arbitration

The government of Alberta could also enhance workers’ ability to exercise their associational rights under the Wagner model by providing for first-contract arbitration (FCA). Essentially, if collective bargaining reaches an impasse when the union and employer are negotiating a first collective agreement, either side can apply for resolution via arbitration, rather than being forced into a strike and/or lockout.

The need for FCA reflects that some employers will stonewall the union during the first round of bargaining in the hope of breaking the union. The purpose of collective bargaining is to reach a mutually agreeable collective agreement, not to allow the employer an opportunity to re-fight the certification campaign. FCA addresses this inappropriate behaviour by eliminating an employer’s incentive to stonewall.

First-contract arbitration is available in most Canadian jurisdictions. Experience (particularly in BC, Ontario and Quebec) suggests the availability of FCA reduces employers’ incentive to stonewall unions to such a degree that FCA is rarely invoked.

4. Sectoral Bargaining

The final change Alberta could make to enhance workers’ ability to exercise their associational rights under the Wagner model is to expand sectoral bargaining. Sectoral bargaining allows a union to negotiate a single collective agreement that covers multiple worksites and/or employers. When new worksites or employers are unionized, they become subject to the master agreement.

Internationally, there are many examples of sectoral bargaining in developed countries, including Argentina, Brazil, many European Union countries, South Africa, and South Korea. Most provinces (including Alberta) use sectoral unionization in the construction industry, where often employers are small and work is transitory.

Sectoral bargaining addresses the difficulties workers in small enterprises face in exercising their associational rights. In Canada, 98% of all employers are small enterprises (<100 employees), and small enterprises employ two-thirds of private-sector workers. Organizing and subsequently bargaining and administering a collective agreement in small workplaces is a relatively high-cost undertaking, for both the union and the employer.

In addition to the higher cost of organizing small enterprises, the lack of organizational distance between workers and employers in small enterprises also reduces the anonymity of union supporters. This makes certification drives riskier for workers and more prone to failure.

Canadian sectoral bargaining typically only affects employers for whom a union has been certified. There are, however, other models. Some European jurisdictions allow for the extension of the agreement to other parties in some circumstances. In Quebec, collective agreements in the construction industry apply to all employers and workers. Quebec labour legislation also provides for decrees that extend provisions of collective agreements across an industrial sector, such as the automotive services sector in Montreal.

Sectoral bargaining also acts to remove wage costs from competition: all affected employers are subject to the same contact and, therefore, have the same basic labour costs. This forces employers to compete on productivity, efficiency and quality, rather than cheap labour.

To date, there has been no research about how sectoral bargaining affects unionization rates, most likely because there have been no “natural experiments” to observe. The logic of sectoral bargaining is, however, compelling. Allowing unions to negotiate multi-employer agreements reduces the costs associated with organizing small workplaces. The introduction of card-check certification provisions should reduce the risk of certification to workers in small workplace and increase the likelihood of successful drives. Together, these changes should increase the ability and willingness of workers in small enterprises to access union representation.

5. Minority Unionism

Under the Wagner system, unions are organized on the principle of exclusive majority unionism. In essence, only one union can represent a group (or class of workers) at a single employer’s worksite, and that union must be selected via a formal certification by a majority of those workers.

One effect of exclusive majority unionism is that there tends to be a gap between the demand for union representation and workers’ access to it. For example, some workers will want to be represented by a union but will be unable to convince a majority of their colleagues to support unionization. As we saw above, about a third of non-unionized Canadian workers fall into this category.

Some labour commentators suggest that the exclusive majority unionism adopted by provincial labour legislation may be unconstitutional because it denies some workers any way to meaningfully exercise their freedom of association, as required by s.2(d) of the Charter of Rights and Freedoms. Essentially, unless these workers can convince a majority of their co-workers to support a union, they have no vehicle by which to meaningfully associate.

An alternative to exclusive majority unionism is some form of minority unionism.

Minority unionism extends bargaining and grievance-handling rights to unions representing less than a majority of workers in workplaces without an existing union. This approach allows workers to meaningfully exercise their associational rights even when they cannot achieve certification under the traditional Wagner model of certification.

Minority unionism also allows unions to organize workers at lower cost and risk. Worksites organized in this manner could then be converted to certified worksites in the future.

Minority unionism might legislatively build upon protections offered to US workers engaged in concerted activity by the National Labour Relations Act (NLRA). Section 7 of the NLRA provides protection to persons engaged in “concerted activity” for the purpose of “mutual aid or protection,” such as the recent “Fight for 15” campaigns by non-union workers across the United States.

These protections are broader than those usually accorded to workers in Canadian labour laws. For example, the protections set out in Sections 21, 148 and 149 of Alberta’s Labour Relations Code are focused mostly on the formation of or participation in a union. Other associational activity is not protected.

In his 2012 study, David Doorey suggests an approach he calls graduated freedom of association, wherein unorganized workers would have the statutory right to form associations and make representations to the employers about conditions of work. Employers would be obligated to engage in meaningful dialogue and in good faith as well as be precluded from reprisals against workers. The definition of worker might be broadened to “person” to open up minority unionism to non-employees (for example, independent contractors). 

This blog is based on Bob Barnetson's presentation "Overcoming legal barriers to fair labour practice" at Parkland Institute's 2015 fall conference.

Bob Barnetson

Dr. Bob Barnetson is a professor of labour relations at Athabasca University. His research focuses on the political economy of workplace regulation in Alberta with specific attention to occupational injury, child labour and farm worker rights. Barnetson is the author of several Parkland Institute reports and blog posts. His recent books include Canadas labour market training system (Athabasca U Press, 2018), Farm workers in Alberta (UAlberta Press, 2016), and Health and safety in Canadian workplaces (Athabasca U Press, 2016).

Read more by this author |  Follow on Twitter

Related reading

Get timely research and analysis from Parkland in your inbox.

Subscribe to email from Parkland

Your donation supports research for the common good.

Donate to Parkland Institute
end include: pages_show_blog_post_wide